Peppercom research analyst Milos Sugovic posted the other day about the faltering fortunes of Starbucks. Milos pointed out that in a market characterized by monopolistic competition, where there are many producers and consumers, few barriers to entry, and product differentiation via branding, Starbucks’ profits were doomed in an economic downturn.
During good times, consumers were willing to pay $4 for a cup of coffee because they found it more expensive in terms of time and effort required to find the “best” product than to simply take the convenient route and stop at one of numerous local Starbucks shops. In other words, consumers chose not to gather the data needed to make an informed buying decision.
Milos’ post set off a pointed discussion here at Peppercom between him and senior analyst Matt Purdue.
Matt: The fact that companies caught up in monopolistic competition make it cumbersome for consumers to gather information seems valid, and this gets to the heart of PR. It seems as if these companies rely on information asymmetry. If consumers really could (or would) arm themselves with enough information, they could make intelligent decisions. If more consumers knew that Consumer Reports actually ranked McDonald’s coffee quality ahead of Starbucks’, the latter would have a hard time justifying their $4 java. But Starbucks would never want to divulge such information. In fact, their reliance on information asymmetry might make them a challenging PR client indeed.
Milos: I’d be careful about saying that companies “make” it cumbersome for consumers to gather information. The nature of the market (monopolistic competition) is such that there are many producers whose goods are differentiated by brand. Comparing them is inherently costly for consumers due to sheer numbers, not because the companies make it so. And because product consumption such as coffee generates only low marginal utility, the cost of information gathering, processing and decision-making is too high. In other words, seeking out the best cup of coffee has a high opportunity cost. So producers a la Starbucks take advantage of the market characteristics and consumer behavior under time/budgetary constraints.
Matt: I think it’s a bit naïve to think that companies don’t want to keep consumers in the dark in a commoditized market. Why did the New York State Restaurant Association spend five years and thousands of dollars to defeat state legislation to require nutritional labels on menus? You suggest that for consumers the act of information gathering is too high, but I would argue it is kept artificially high. So who makes it too high?
The companies realize the nature of the market they’re in, and know that consumers aren’t deciding on price. So the companies take that as an opportunity to control the flow of information consumers get. You say they do it through branding and advertising. I would suggest they also control it through obfuscation.
I can fairly easily find out dealer invoice for a new Subaru, but god help me if I try to find out how many calories are in a Chipotle burrito (a lot). Burp.
Milos: I agree and disagree with you, depending on which markets/goods we’re talking about. My point is: it doesn’t take much/any effort for Starbucks to keep consumers in the dark. It’d take a lot of time just to find out all the coffee prices on our street here, and Starbucks is betting that most consumers will not engage in price shopping. Granted, as the goods become more expensive, the incentive to gather information (beyond just price) increases, and so too does the need to artificially keep the cost of information gathering high. At the end of the day, it’s hard to generalize across all product categories. I’m still focusing solely on coffee.
Matt: I’d argue that it’s not so hard for consumers to compare coffee. In New York, we walk by 15 coffee places on our way to work. In this type of market where, again, price is not an issue, it’s relatively easy to try a different coffee every morning. Same goes for people who drive to work. I imagine they pass any number of coffee mongers on their commute.
Obviously, Starbucks realizes this and floods the market with shops. And, of course, makes the brand and the experience so compelling that people identify very strongly with it.
Bottom line is the Starbucks brand actually made a $4 cup of an inexpensive product a very reasonable expense for millions of people for a very long time. They should be in the Harvard Business School Hall of Fame. In their hearts, consumers know they are getting swindled, and they know it would be easy to find comparable coffee…but the brand is just so powerful, they don’t do it.